To ensure the widest possible dissemination of our methodology, we have established a country risk homepage:
../../Country_Risk
This site includes the most recent estimates of the expected returns for 135 countries as well as the associated hitting time measures.
A simple, and well known, approach to systematic risk is the beta of the Sharpe (1964), Lintier (1965) and Black (1970) Capital Asset Pricing Model. This model was initially presented and applied to U.S. data. The classic empirical studies, such as Fama and MacBeth (1973), Gibbons (1982) and Stambaugh (1982) presented some evidence in support of the formulation. This model was brought to an international setting by Solnik (1974a,b, 1977). The risk factor is no longer the U.S. market portfolio but the world market portfolio.
The evidence on using the beta factor as a country risk measure in an international context is mixed. The early studies find it difficult to reject a model which relates average beta risk to average returns. For example, Harvey and Zhou (1993) find it difficult to reject a positive relation between beta risk and expected returns in 18 markets. However, when more general models are examined, the evidence against the model becomes stronger. Harvey (1991) presents evidence against the world CAPM when both risks and expected returns are allowed to change through time. Ferson and Harvey (1993) extend this analysis to a multifactor formulation which follows the work of Ross (1976) and Sharpe (1982). Their model also allows for dynamic risk premiums and risk exposures.
The bottom line for these studies is that the beta approach has some merit when applied in developed markets. The beta, whether measured against a single factor or against multiple world sources of risk, appears to have some ability to discriminate between expected returns. The work of Ferson and Harvey (1994, 1995) is directed at modeling the conditional risk functions for developed capital markets. They show how to introduce economic variables, fundamental measures, and both local and world wide information into dynamic risk functions. However, their work only applies to 21 developed equity markets. What about the other 114 countries?
Bekaert and Harvey (1995a) pursue a model where expected returns are influenced by both world factors (like a world CAPM) and local factors (like a CAPM which holds only in that country). They propose a conditional regime switching methodology which allows the country to evolve from a developing segmented country to a developing country which is integrated in world capital markets.
The Bekaert and Harvey (1995a) is very promising and they have applied this idea to the cost of capital estimation for individual securities in emerging markets [see Bekaert and Harvey (1995b).] However, all of the estimation is calibrated using the data for only the 20 developing markets collected by the International Finance Corporation.
It is straightforward to estimate a relation (the "reward for risk") between, say, a beta and expected return. The cost of capital is obtained by multiplying this reward for risk times the beta. The beta is measured by analyzing the way the equity returns covary with a benchmark return. What if there is no equity market? That is, even if we estimate the risk premium using the 47 countries where data is available, we have no way of using the reward for risk because we do not have betas for many of the developing economies' markets -- because the equity market does not yet exist.
Our country credit ratings source is Institutional Investor's semi-annual survey of bankers. Institutional Investor has published this survey in its March and September issues every year since 1979. The survey represents the responses of 75-100 bankers. Respondents rate each country on a scale of 0 to 100, with 100 representing the smallest risk of default. Institutional Investor weights these responses by its perception of each bank's level of global prominence and credit analysis sophistication [see Shapiro (1994) and Erb, Harvey and Viskanta (1994, 1995)].
How do credit ratings translate into perceived risk and where do country ratings come from? Most globally-oriented banks have credit analysis staffs. Their charter is to estimate the probability of default on their bank's loans. One dimension of this analysis is the estimation of sovereign credit risk. The higher the perceived credit risk of a borrower's home country, the higher the rate of interest that the borrower will have to pay. There are many factors that simultaneously influence a country credit rating: political and other expropriation risk, inflation, exchange-rate volatility and controls, the nation's industrial portfolio, its economic viability, and its sensitivity to global economic shocks, to name some of the most important.
The credit rating, because it is survey based, may proxy for many of these fundamental risks. Through time, the importance of each of these fundamental components may vary. Most importantly, lenders are concerned with future risk. In contrast to traditional measurement methodologies which look back in history, a credit rating is forward looking.
Our idea is to fit a model using the equity data in 47 countries and the associated credit ratings. Using the estimated reward to credit risk measure, we will forecast "out-of-sample" the expected rates of return in the 88 which do not have equity markets.
The equity returns presented in Table 1 are calculated in U.S. dollars. This is especially appropriate in the segmented developing markets where the evidence in Liew (1995) suggests that purchasing power parity closely holds. There are a wide range of average returns and volatility in this sample. Some of the most extreme average returns are found in the newly added markets (Poland and Hungary). Unfortunately, there is only a short sample of equity returns available for these countries.
Table 1 also presents the correlation with the world portfolio calculated over the full sample and over the last five years. The beta with respect to the world market index is also presented. This beta is an appropriate ex ante measure of risk if:
We estimate the following linear model
where R is the semi-annual return in U.S. dollars for country I, CCR is the country credit rating which is available at the end of March and the end of September each year, t is measured in half years and epsilon is the regression residual. We estimate a time-series cross-sectional regression by combining all the countries and credit ratings into one large model. In this sense, the coefficient is the "reward for risk." Consistent with asset pricing traditions, this reward for risk is world-wide -- it is not specific to a particular country.
This model forces a linear relation between credit rating and expected returns. Intuition suggests that a linear model may not be appropriate. That is, as credit rating gets very low, expected returns may go up faster than a linear model may suggest. Indeed, at very low credit ratings, such as the Sudan, it may be unlikely that any hurdle rate is acceptable to the multinational corporation considering a direct investment project.
We present two alternative formulations which capture the potential nonlinearity at low credit ratings. The first model is a log-linear model, i.e. the natural log of the CCR is used in the regression (log model). The second model uses the inverse of the CCR (risk model) We call this last model the risk model because a high factor implies a higher risk. Whereas in the other models, a higher factor implies a lower risk. These alternative models are
In the linear model and the log model, the slope coefficient should be negative implying a higher credit rating is associated with lower average returns. In the risk regression, the slope coefficient should be positive.
We are also interested in any differences in the reward for risk across different markets. We estimate augmented versions of these models. The log model is:
This superscripts D and E denote emerging and developed markets respectively. The model allows for different rewards for credit risk depending on the type of market.
Finally, we fit the identical specifications to explain the variance of the returns over the period:
where sigma is the unconditional standard deviation of the monthly returns six months after the credit rating is observed.
We also estimated a conditional beta model which follows Shanken (1990) and Ferson and Harvey (1991, 1995). The model is:
where the asterisk denotes the log demeaned credit rating. This interaction term tells us the impact of credit rating on the risk. The last two columns in Table 1 report the slope coefficients. While the coefficient on the interaction term is negative in 33 of the 47 markets (lower credit rating means higher risk), it is clear that this formulation is insufficient to explain the return patterns in the developing markets.
Figure 2 presents the average returns five years following the observation of a standard deviation against the beta. There is a weak positive relation observed here. Higher standard deviation is associated with higher returns. This is particularly the case among the emerging equity markets and is consistent with the economic model proposed in Bekaert and Harvey (1995a).
As mentioned earlier, both of these models are problematic when going to the other 88 countries. In those countries, there is no way to estimate a beta coefficient or volatility. Even if significant coefficient were obtained, however, this framework is problematic because data on the determining attribute (equity risk) is not available for a broader set of countries.
There are a number of observations from this graph. First, even within the sample of equity returns, the linear model does not seem appropriate. The fitted values for the highest rated countries (like Switzerland) are too low compared to the average returns. The fitted values for the lowest rated countries are also too low. This is immediate evidence of nonlinearity.
Both the log and risk model appear to capture this nonlinearity. The difference between the two models is most evident at the very low credit risk points. In this region, the risk model gives much higher fitted values. It is difficult to judge the model in this region because we are in "no man's land". That is, there are no observations of the dependent variable available for a reasonableness check. However, this is a problem that we inevitably face when trying to estimate the cost of capital for all countries in the world.
It turns out that the split sample regression offers little compared to the full sample regression. The coefficients on the credit rating variable for developed countries and the credit rating variable on the developing countries is indistinguishable. In addition, the amount of variance explained, adjusted for the number of regressors, is lower with the augmented model. The fitted values are presented in Figure 4. Notice that the log model (fit on the developed country returns) and extended to the emerging returns is very similar in to the model estimated on the emerging market returns. This analysis suggests that the reward for credit risk is not different across emerging and developed markets.
In order to calculate hitting times, we need both the ex ante expected return and variance. The results of estimating the volatility models are presented in Table 4. The format is identical to Table 2. Three models are presented. In the final analysis, the log of country credit rating shows the most promise in explaining the cross-section and time-series of semi-annual returns.
There is one difference between the results for the expected returns and the volatilities. There appears to be more of a difference between developed countries and developing countries. Although credit rating is strongly negatively related to expected returns in both groups of countries, the magnitude of the coefficient is greater in emerging markets (-0.0323 versus -0.0285). In economic terms, a ten point drop in credit rating would increase volatility by 6.6% points in a developed market and 7.4%points in an emerging market. Nevertheless, the two coefficients are only one standard error from each other.
The idea of hitting time is to fix the probability, the expected returns and the volatility, and to calculate how long it would take to achieve a certain return. We choose two hurdles: break-even and doubling of investment. We ask how long it will take to achieve these hurdles with 90% confidence. We make the assumption that the distribution of data is normal. It is possible to make other assumptions about the distribution of returns. Indeed, it is also possible to use the historical returns as the empirical distribution and by using Monte Carlo methods answer the same question.
The hitting times have a wide range of values depending on the country examined. For example, it takes almost two years for the investment in Afghanistan to break even with 90% confidence. This amount of time may be too long for an investor worried about the potentially volatile downside political and economic risk. On the other hand, the U.S. takes a little over 4 years to break even with 90% probability. One has to wait 16 years for the investment to double in value with 90% confidence.
The country credit rating might subsume some of these measures. For example, the correlation between the country credit ratings and the ICRG political risk ratings reported in Diamonte, Liew and Stevens is 88%.
The other contribution of the paper is to examine the investment process. In segmented capital markets, it is not appropriate to use the beta of the country with respect to the world market portfolio as a measure of risk. Indeed, a misapplication of this methodology could lead to gross underestimates of the cost of capital in segmented equity markets.
The method we propose to forecast expected returns and volatility is very simple and parsimonious. Importantly, it is not necessarily the best model for expected returns and volatility. Unfortunately, because of the nature of the problem, there is no way to verify the accuracy of the results until some of the developing countries "emerge" into the MSCI or IFC database.
Bekaert, Geert, and Campbell R. Harvey, 1995a, "Emerging equity market volatility," Working paper, Duke University and Stanford University.
Bekaert, Geert, and Campbell R. Harvey, 1995b, "The cost of capital in emerging markets," Working paper, Duke University and Stanford University.
Bekaert, Geert, and Campbell R. Harvey, 1995c, "Emerging capital markets and economic development," Working paper, Duke University and Stanford University.
Black, Fischer, 1972, "Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing," Journal of Business 45, 444-455.
Diamonte, Robin, John M. Liew and Ross L. Stevens, "Political risk in emerging and developed markets," Working paper, Goldman Sachs and Company, New York, NY.
Erb, Claude, Campbell R. Harvey and Tadas Viskanta, 1994, "National risk and global fixed income allocation," Journal of Fixed Income September, 17-26.
Erb, Claude, Campbell R. Harvey and Tadas Viskanta, 1995, "Country credit risk and global portfolio selection," Journal of Portfolio Management 9, Winter, 74-83.
Errunza, Vihang R., and Etienne Losq, 1985, "International asset pricing under mild segmentation: Theory and test," Journal of Finance 40, 105--124.
Fama, Eugene F. and James D. MacBeth, 1973, "Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests," Journal of Political Economy 81, 607-636.
Ferson, Wayne E., and Campbell R. Harvey, 1991, "The variation of economic risk premiums," Journal of Political Economy 99, 285-315.
Ferson, Wayne E., and Campbell R. Harvey, 1993, "The risk and predictability of international equity returns," Review of Financial Studies 6, 527--566.
Ferson, Wayne E., and Campbell R. Harvey, 1994, "An exploratory investigation of the fundamental determinants of national equity market returns," in Jeffrey Frankel, ed.: The Internationalization of Equity Markets, (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL), 59--138.
Ferson, Wayne E., and Campbell R. Harvey, 1994, "Country risk in asset pricing tests," Working paper, Duke University.
Gibbons, Michael R., 1982, "Multivariate tests of financial models: A new approach," Journal of Financial Economics 10, 3-27.
Harvey, Campbell R., 1991, "The world price of covariance risk," Journal of Finance 46, 111--157.
Harvey, Campbell R., 1993, "Portfolio enhancement with emerging markets and conditioning information," in Stijn Claessens, and Sudarshan Gooptu, eds.: Portfolio investment in developing countries, (World Bank, Washington), 110--144.
Harvey, Campbell R., 1995, "Predictable risk and returns in emerging markets," Review of Financial Studies 8, 773-816.
Harvey, Campbell R., Bruno H. Solnik, and Guofu Zhou, 1994, "What determines expected international asset returns?," Working paper, Duke University, Durham, NC.
Harvey, Campbell R. and Guofu Zhou, 1993, "International asset pricing with alternative distributional assumptions," Journal of Empirical Finance 1, 107-131.
Liew, John M., "Stock returns, inflation, and the volatility of growth in the money supply: Evidence from emerging markets," Working paper, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL.
Lintner, John, 1965, "The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets," Review of Economics and Statistics 47, 13--37.
Ross, Stephen A., 1976, "The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing," Journal of Economic Theory 13, 341-360.
Shanken, Jay, 1990, "Intertemporal asset pricing: An empirical investigation," Journal of Econometrics 45, 99--120.
Sharpe, William, 1964, "Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk," Journal of Finance 19, 425--442.
Solnik, Bruno, 1974, "An equilibrium model of the international capital market," Journal of Economic Theory 8, 500--524.
Solnik, Bruno, 1974b "The international pricing of risk: An empirical investigation of the world capital market structure," Journal of Finance 29, 48--54.
Solnik, Bruno, 1977, "Testing international asset pricing: Some pessimistic views," Journal of Finance 32 (1977), 503--511.
Solnik, Bruno, 1983, "The relationship between stock prices and inflationary expectations: The international evidence," Journal of Finance 38, 35--48.
Solnik, Bruno, 1983, "International arbitrage pricing theory," Journal of Finance 38, 449--457.
Stambaugh, Robert F., 1982, "On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two parameter model: A sensitivity analysis," Journal of Financial Economics 10, 237-268.
Stehle, Richard, 1977, "An empirical test of the alternative hypotheses of national and international pricing of risky assets," Journal of Finance 32, 493--502.
Stulz, Rene, 1981a, "On the effects of barriers to international investment," Journal of Finance 36, 923-934.
Stulz, Rene, 1981b, "A model of international asset pricing," Journal of Financial Economics 9, 383-406.
World Bank, 1993, Emerging stock markets factbook, (International Finance Corporation, Washington, D.C.).